2.7
Economic Consideration
2.7.1 Introduction:
The regional trend of electricity sector reform is being
driven largely by the perceived benefits in terms of improved economic efficiency,
lower electricity prices, and access to much needed capital to fund
infrastructural growth. Apart from a few cases, reform is replacing vertically-
integrated structures with ones in which there are vertically and horizontally
disaggregated competitive elements.
While the maximization of economic efficiency is a primary
goal, security of supply is another interacting consideration of some
importance. In developed economies with established energy infrastructures,
demand growth tends to be relatively low, and in many instances significant
generation over-capacity has existed over the last few years. With market
liberalization, this reserve capacity has tended to diminish substantially,
leading to public concern about supply security, especially with respect to
potential disruptions (which can result from abnormal weather patterns, natural
hazards, or a mechanical failure of some kind in the supply system). In
developing economies, security of supply is also a major issue, but for a
different reason. In many cases, capacity growth can’t keep up with the
potential demand, and an urgent requirement exists to draw more capital into
the sector to improve the adequacy of the electricity supply system, and hence
supply security. Market liberalization in this situation, may be seen as a
means of increasing investment in the sector, and hence bolstering security.
2.7.2 Conventional
Electricity Sector Structure:
Historically, it has been assumed that a
vertically-integrated, state-owned monopoly would deliver electricity at least
cost, and with the greatest degree of security. Because electricity was
considered a strategic asset, and security of supply was vital during the
industrializing process, there was some merit in this idea. It also made sense
to believe that it was much more efficient to have electricity dispatched and
delivered by internal commands within one organization. This idea was rooted in
the fact that electricity is no ordinary product – the electrons cannot be
stored in large quantities, and supply must match the load from instant to
instant to maintain the voltage and frequency within acceptable limits.
In a vertically-integrated business, costs are
internalized. Vertical desegregation raises the issue of the transaction costs
imposed by the need for upstream to downstream products and services to be
negotiated through contracts.
2.7.3 Efficiency Gain in
Competitive Market:
Although vertically-integrated, bureaucratic structures can
be efficient at undertaking certain functions, significant inefficiencies can
creep in over time due to the lack of competitive pressure and efficiency
benchmarks, and a lack of transparency. Because of the nature of the
electricity industry, requiring a high degree of contingency capability, the
generation capacity of state operated systems in many economies were typically
“gold plated”. Many instances can be found where generation facilities existed
solely for contingency purposes, and to manage infrequent peak demand
situations.
Another source of cost reduction relates to fuel choice,
and more specifically to attempts to maintain security of supply by favoring
one particular fuel through subsidization. When a cheaper fuel becomes
available, regulations designed to protect certain fuels become an obstacle to
overall cost reduction. Coal has usually been protected through subsidies on
price, or through regulations preventing alternatives. In the UK prior to
deregulation, the relatively expensive domestic coal was subsidized, and gas
was barred from use in generation. After deregulation, the “dash for gas”
brought about not only a large shift from coal-fired generation to gas combined
cycle generation, but substantial savings in fuel costs.
There are also considerable cost savings possible from
improvements of performance in the existing generation, transmission and
distribution system. In the past, little incentive existed to replace old,
inefficient plant, as costs were not overly transparent. Generation plants have
traditionally been kept in operation well past their commercial lifetime, which
can be long anyway, so, a lot of old infrastructure exists in the sector.
Of great significance today in the sector are the
efficiencies now available through recent technological advances. Combined
cycle gas turbines are available “off-the shelf” at much lower capital cost per
MW than most other forms of plant. These allow small-scale units to be quickly
installed, and providing the gas is available, allow for flexibility in
sitting. CCGT plants are leading the trend towards more distributed forms of
power, a trend that may gather significant momentum in the decades ahead, with
consequences for the established network infrastructure.
Technology has also had a very large impact on the
processes of dispatching and wholesale pooling. Wholesale markets can now be
set up easily and cheaply, and can be operated at a distance using the Internet
and other electronic means of communication. As long as the market participants
agree to the rules, it can operate with high efficiency. Dispatching can be
handled just as easily and efficiency, regardless of firm ownership.
2.7.4 Power Supply Industry
Cost Structure:
The power generation sector has the largest share in terms
of total electricity supply cost, and so is likely to be the major source of
cost reduction. As seen in the table below, in case of the practical ways, the
generation sector shared about 65% of the total supply cost of electricity.
Function
|
Fraction of Total Cost
|
1. Generation
|
65%
|
2. Transmission
|
10%
|
3. Distribution
|
20%
|
4. Supply
|
5%
|
Table 2.2 Structure of the power sector supply chain
2.8 Stranded Costs
2.8.1 What is stranded Costs?
Stranded costs can be defined as costs utilities have
incurred historically, but may not be able to recover in the prices they are
able to charge as a result of policy changes. In order to meet national and
public service obligations, many utilities, both public and private, have made
substantial investments - including the construction of nuclear power plants. A
significant percentage of this investment may not be recoverable in a
competitive environment. The term, ‘strandable’ may be more suitable than
‘stranded’ as some part of past investments may be recovered over time.
In all states the level of utility profit was tied to the
level of capital investment made by the utility. As profit would increase with
amount of invested capital, utilities had an incentive to maximize their
capital investment, so long as they could show that it was “prudent” and
providing benefits to consumers. Given this regulatory framework, not all
utility expenditures have been wise investments. Stranded costs represent a
significant policy problem, especially where attempts have been made to recover
these costs over the short-term by allowing retail electricity prices to rise
significantly above marginal costs. The difference between the current low
marginal cost of electricity generation and existing tariff rates set to cover
the past investment has been a major driving force for the introduction of
competition. As the difference becomes greater and more apparent, consumers are
likely to leave incumbent electric power suppliers in an attempt to lower their
electricity bills. In this case, the investment cost may not be recovered by
those utilities that made large capital investment in generation and networks
under a past regulatory regime.
Stranded costs are of great importance to economies in
transition to competition because the financial burden can be very large, no
matter who bears it. If government is held responsible for the debt such as in
the ‘regulatory compact’ argument, it would be redistributed as a tax on all
citizens. If electricity consumers are forced to pay the debt (through higher
tariffs), this creates an un-level playing field with respect to new entrants not
burdened by these costs. The utilities straddled with this burden under free
market conditions will likely suffer serious financial losses, possibly leading
to bankruptcy.
Classic examples are nuclear power plants in the United
States. Early retirement of most nuclear plants to date has uncovered a number
of factors that deserve attention. One problem is the inability to collect
funds for the decommissioning of plants that have been (or will be) retired
early, preventing the accumulation of sufficient funds to manage the
decommissioning process. This problem exists largely because of a gross
underestimation of decommissioning costs. For example, interim waste storage
costs have not been adequately reflected in decommissioning trust funds in the
United States, and nuclear decommissioning liabilities in general were not
financially covered. As seen in the case of the decommissioning of Yankee Rowe
in Massachusetts, which was retired early, the cost over-run in decommissioning
created serious financial problems for utilities as well as regulators.
Some economies may face the stranded costs problem with
respect to nuclear plants sooner or later. In particular, nuclear power
generation, and may find it difficult to avoid this issue in the future if
these plants prove to be uneconomic in a competitive environment. The problem
could be heightened if nuclear power plants must be shut down earlier than
originally planned, for reasons other than economic ones.
2.8.2 Types of Stranded Cost:
There are four main types of stranded costs. The first
results from a combination of increased competition and technology development,
which brings in new competitors with cheaper electricity production capacities
than existing plants. These new competitors could put old plants out of business
by charging customers less for the electricity generated.
The second type originates from
long-term fuel or power purchasing contracts with governments to which
regulated utilities are committed to ensure security of electricity supply. As
competition could provide lower cost alternatives, those utilities tied to
uneconomic obligations would inevitably be faced with higher input costs,
resulting in loss of earnings. Eventually this will make cost recovery
difficult.
The third type is associated
with “regulatory assets.” Regulatory assets are an assortment of
regulator-approved ‘extended payment plans’ for certain kinds of large
expenditure incurred by regulated utilities. Easing utilities’ financial
obligations from such expenditure, regulators allow them to amortize costs over
an extended period of time. However if the regulatory regime changes during the
middle of the amortization period, utilities may not be able to complete the
amortization due to deregulation-induced low prices.
The fourth type of stranded
costs are miscellaneous public-policy programs ranging from Demand Side
Management (DSM) programs paid for by all customers, and support for energy
research and development. Investment in all these policy programs would be
stranded as their cost recovery becomes impossible after deregulation.
2.8.3 Stranded Cost Estimation:
Stranded costs are differences between the projected and
realized net values of an investment, taking into account revenues and
expenditures, which come into being where retail electricity prices are above
marginal costs. When utilities cannot produce electricity at prices equal to
marginal costs, customers are likely to leave them for other utilities, putting
investment at risk of being stranded.
Fig 2.7 Graph between RR and MV |
Estimation of stranded cost seems simple, but is
complicated in practice due to a number of factors. Among them are the
projected market prices of electricity, operating and maintenance costs
including fuel prices, interest rates, technology development, and government
regulations, to list a few. For example, rising fuel prices for inefficient
facilities3 would shift the RR curve in Figure upward, which will lead to
higher stranded costs. The same is true of rising interest rates. Thus
projections of stranded costs for a single economy could vary widely with
assumptions about these variables.
Stranded
cost could be calculated with the following formula:
Stranded Cost (SC) =
Required Revenue (RR) – Market Value (MV) – where;
RR = g{Load Factor (-), Fuel
Cost (+), Interest Rates (+), Deferred Cost (+), etc}, and
MV= f{Avoided cost (+),
Costs for new entrants (+), etc}
2.8.4 Who Should Bear The Cost:
Presuming that stranded costs are incurred as a result of
regulatory changes, the question of who should bear them becomes a key policy
question. The utilities who made investments under pressure from regulatory
agencies - over and above what would be prudent in a free market - and who are
looking to recover these costs to the greatest extent possible, argue that they
must be fully compensated, because the investment decision was forced on them
at the request of governments.4 At the time of the investment, an ‘implicit
social contract’, was made to ensure full recovery of investment costs.
Contracts, however detailed, cannot cover all contingencies, mandating cost
recovery in the event of a regulatory regime change. Further it has been argued
that deregulatory actions constitute the government’s taking of private
property, which was prohibited under the Constitution’. This is known as a
“taking” argument in favor of full recovery of stranded costs.
Regulators have argued that the chance of non-recovery of
costs was just as implicit in the contract because contracts (in these case,
franchise agreements) do not explicitly specify liability for stranded costs.
Further they claim there is evidence in the contracts made under regulation
that regulators never prevented utilities from recovering costs, but on the
contrary encouraged this. The existence of contracts that specified a minimum
term for customers to stay with a particular utility or face cancellation
charges for service termination has strengthened their argument.
There is no easy solution to this issue as every contract
was made under different circumstances, and interpretations even with respect
to a particular contract could differ quite substantially. Both legal and
economic reasoning could help address this problem. On a spectrum between no
compensation and full compensation, most experts take the middle ground, suggesting
that there is an implicit deal in the contract, but it does not necessarily
imply a guarantee of full recovery for the investment made under regulation. In
a nutshell, a general view is that the size of recoverable costs should be
determined on a case-by-case basis, depending on the specific attributes, and
without discouraging cost saving efforts by those who want compensation. If a
fixed rule for cost recovery is applied, utilities may simply shift costs into
the account of stranded costs.
2.8.5 How to Pay for Stranded Cost:
There have been a number of
studies on the ways to recover stranded costs. The most important factors for
consideration include the economic consequences, both in the short and long
run. Given the economic situation there
are a number of ways that have been implemented or suggested. There are other
methods of collecting stranded costs. It is possible to view these strategies
from the perspective of whether they are transaction or non-transaction
related. The classification is as follows:
Transaction-Related Recovery Devices:
·
Access charge tied directly
to continued transmission or distribution service
·
Exit fees charged to
departing customers but unrelated to costs incurred on behalf of those
customers
·
Exit fees charged to
departing customers and calculated to recover costs incurred on behalf of those
customers
·
A share of net generation
savings realized by departing customers over time
Non-Transaction-Related Recovery Devices
·
Shifting costs to captive
customers
·
Charging ratepayers above-cost
prices where market exceeds cost
·
Accelerated and decelerated
depreciation
·
Price cap on
performance-based rates
Broader Bases
·
Entrance fees charged to new
generation
·
All sellers pay a per-kWh
tax on generation
·
Taxes to include credits for
financial write-downs or trust funds to subsidize buyout of contracts from
non-utility generators
There is no best way for all cases. Each of the above 11
strategies has to be evaluated to determine its applicability in comparison
with other strategies considering differences in economies or regions. The
criteria must include consideration of static and dynamic efficiency,
consistency with evolution to a competitive market, consistency with regulatory
and difficulties in implementation.
2.8.6 Security of Supply:
The question of supply security has been much debated
within economies undertaking electricity sector reform. Two issues are
important, the securing of long-term supplies of generation fuels at affordable
prices, and the reliability of the electricity system. The maintenance of
adequate generation reserve capacity is a component of the system reliability
concern.
The introduction of competition into electricity generation
results in strong pressure to reduce investment and operating costs. The
incentives to void over-building and over-designing power plants, and to reduce
operation and maintenance costs, raises the possibility that reserve capacities
could drop to levels well below what is prudent to manage contingency
situations.
Arguments about reserve capacity can be considered a component of
long-term reliability, which requires the planning and the construction of
enough aggregate capacity (generating and network) to balance total demand and
supply at prevailing prices at all times. Short-term reliability requires
adequate reaction to load fluctuations over time scales ranging from
microseconds to months.
Reliability in De-regulated Power Markets:
Electricity sector reform has had a short history worldwide.
Although some economies undertook partial reform measures during the 1970s and
1980s, most substantial reform has occurred in the 1990s. This leaves a very
short timeframe over which to try and assess whether the impacts with respect
to the overall reliability of the system will be positive or negative. This
question will also obviously be affected by policy decisions made in the near
term to address real or perceived problems in this area.
From a theoretical perspective, appropriate market signals with
respect to the need for additional generation capacity or network upgrading,
along with market incentives to maintain the provision of high quality
services, should ensure sustainable and efficient allocation of capital. If
true competition develops through the supply chain, suppliers will compete to provide
a range of products and services, including the level security of supply
demanded by customers.
Electricity Prices for Industrial Customers:
Deregulation in the electricity industry is considered to have
brought efficiency improvements in industrial sectors as well as in related
sectors. Evidence suggests electricity price reductions have occurred in the
industrial sector in some economies.
With regard to the availability and reliability of electricity sold
by utilities, large industrial companies may prefer to build their own
electricity generation on-site. This is often the case for the pulp and paper
and chemical industries. Some economies also set their regulations to provide
incentives for industries to develop self-generation.
In India, a number of industrial companies that have on-site
cogeneration plants have excess capacity, and are able to sell their surplus
electricity to the national grid. The impact of restructuring on the future of
cogeneration systems will be influenced by the wholesale price of electricity.
A lower market price may discourage manufacturers to build generation capacity,
while higher price may increase incentives for cogeneration, especially for
small industries with small electricity loads.
Transparency:
In a fully competitive market, all electricity consumers should be
able to choose their retail supplier, based on price and/or quality of services
provided. In such a situation, consumers need good price and service
information, in order to make informed purchase choices. In the past,
electricity bills were normally comprised of a tariff and delivery charge, and
this is still a widespread practice.
No comments:
Post a Comment